Source: https://www.rt.com/op-ed/423921-putin-economy-russia-capitalism/
By: Steve Keen is an Australian economist and author. He’s professor and Head of the School of Economics, History and Politics at Kingston University in London. You can support his attempts to build a new economics https://www.patreon.com/ProfSteveKeen.
The Overnight Transition to
Capitalism
By: Steve Keen is an Australian economist and author. He’s professor and Head of the School of Economics, History and Politics at Kingston University in London. You can support his attempts to build a new economics https://www.patreon.com/ProfSteveKeen.
Russian President Vladimir Putin is reviled as a "bad
person" in the Western press and by Western politicians. And those
accusations have heightened since the Skripal poisoning incident, which has
been blamed on the Kremlin.
I'm neither going to dispute, nor support that characterization.
Instead, I want to give some background as to why a "bad
person" or "strongman" or, indeed, a
hyper patriot, might have been elected Russia's leader in the first place. In
other words, I want to explain why Putin has pursued certain policies which
have helped to prompt such emotional reactions from many Western analysts.
And elected he was, first in 2000 – when, though the elections were
criticized, they were regarded as broadly democratic. He has since been elected
another three times, though Russia is no longer regarded as a true democracy by
much of the West's media and political establishments.
The Bolshevik Experiment
No story starts yesterday, especially with Russia. The latest date
one should commence with is 1914, when Russia was ruled by a hereditary emperor whose political ineptness helped
lead to the First World War. The many disasters that flowed from WWI led to
Nicholas II's own overthrow in 1917 when, after a bloody civil war, the
Bolshevik faction of the Communist Party led by Vladimir Lenin became Russia's
new leaders.
The communist
movement, and its ambition for a different form of social organization to
capitalism, was borne of the harsh conditions of the early period of
industrialization in the West: the phrase "dark Satanic
mills" was coined not by Marx, but by the poet William
Blake, fourteen years before Marx was born. But Marx gave birth to the most
compelling critique of capitalism, as well as, in his typical fashion, an
argument that it was nonetheless a necessary stage in human history. His call
to arms, The Communist Manifesto (co-authored with the
industrialist Engels and published in 1848), was as much a paean to capitalism
as a critique of it.
Capitalism, Marx and Engels observed, had transformed both the
means of production, and the social structure of society. It had replaced
handicrafts with the coal-fire-powered factory system (those "dark,
Satanic mills"). It traded the complicated stratification of
feudal society with, they asserted, just two great opposing social classes:
workers and capitalists.
Both transformations, Marx believed, were necessary precursors to a
better society, and capitalism was their crucible.
In contrast, Lenin's Bolsheviks believed – partly as a side effect
of the accidents of history that gave them power in the first place – that
Russia could leapfrog the capitalist stage of history and bring about "socialism
in one country" via a process of rapid industrialization.
For this they needed a plan, and its essence was provided by the
engineer Grigory Feldman. Working from Marx's division of
industry into one part that produced the "Means of Production" and
another that used these machines to produce consumer goods, Feldman argued
that "promoting the means of production over the means of
consumption" would give backward but socialist Russia a
huge advantage over the advanced capitalist West.
Initially, consumer goods production would be low, and grow more
slowly than investment goods output, so that the population would suffer from
low levels of consumption. But as the means of production expanded far faster
in the Soviet Union than the West, the time would come when the material
prosperity of the workers under socialism in the USSR would far surpass that of
their counterparts under capitalism.
Future party bosses Josef Stalin and Nikita Khrushchev believed
these simulations. They were the basis of Khrushchev's famous claim in 1956
that "we will bury you." He meant that
the material success of socialism would lead the relatively impoverished
working class of the West to demand socialism for themselves. The success of
socialism in one country, Stalin & Khrushchev believed, would lead to
socialism in all.
This material challenge, of course, failed to materialize, and
there were two predominant reasons for it, one very simple and the other rather
more subtle.
The simple reason
was that Feldman's mathematics assumed a limitless supply of peasants who could
become industrial workers. Replacing low productivity fields with the high
productivity factories would cause output to grow very rapidly.
While this assumption held true, Soviet growth did indeed outstrip
the West, and no more so than in the period of Post-WWII reconstruction.
But once all those peasants were fully employed as industrial
workers, the rapid growth in the means of production stopped. Worse still,
Soviet planners continued to prioritize machinery output over consumption
goods, causing per capita consumption to go backwards. The outcome was
queueing: sure, you could buy a TV, or a refrigerator, but it would arrive
years after you made your down-payment.
The workers' response to this was well captured in the Soviet quip
that "they pretend to pay us, and we pretend to work." While
monetary wages were reasonable, the fact that you couldn't buy anything with
that money meant that the pay was often effectively worthless. Growth in
production, already lackluster, slowed even more.
Quality improvement stalled as well, because the Soviet system
lacked the essential stimuli to innovation. As the brilliant Hungarian
economist Janos Kornai put it, Soviet production was "resource
constrained." With all workers fully employed (if faking
work rather than actually doing it), and all factories required to produce to
capacity, the easiest way to come within reach of the ever-rising (and
ever-unmet) output targets of the Five Year Plan was to produce more of last
year's model.
I saw a vivid illustration of this in far-away Australia in 1975,
when my then-girlfriend's brother decided to get a 650cc motorcycle on the
cheap by buying a Soviet Cossack motorbike for A$650, rather than a rival
Japanese motorbike for around A$3,000. Once we unpacked it from its wooden
crate, what stood before us, in all its antique glory, was a 1942 BMW.
Capitalism, by
contrast, was, in Kornai's terms, "demand constrained." With
numerous companies competing for limited demand in most markets, and all having
substantial excess capacity, the best way to capture that demand was to
innovate. The 1975 Honda motorcycle was far more desirable than its 1946 ancestor.
So capitalist industry progressed, interrupted by financial crises,
but still producing more and better goods all the while. In the end, it was not
the workers under capitalism who envied those of socialism, but those trapped
behind the Iron Curtain who envied their Western brethren.
This material failure, and the resource-sapping pressure to
militarily match the aggressive advanced weapons program of the US, set the
grounds for the collapse of the Soviet Union.
These factors also gave rise to a social class that neither Marx
nor Engels anticipated: the Russian mafia. With factory bosses under pressure
to reach impossible targets, and all factories facing shortages of inputs, the
best way to ensure that your factory at least came close to its target was to
buy inputs that "fell off the back" of
the proverbial truck. Thus, access to consumer goods was possible through a
black market as well. A network of criminal suppliers and retailers thus became
an essential lubricant for the creaky wheels of Soviet industry. When the
wheels fell off the Soviet system, the mafia was well placed to take advantage
of it, as were many of the factory bosses with whom they corruptly but
effectively worked.
And the wheels did indeed fall off the socialist truck. Gorbachev's
attempt at reform via Perestroika was too little too late, and resented and
undermined by the old apparatchiks anyway, to the level of a failed coup. The
growing social unrest exceeded the capacity of the weakened repressive elements
of the regime to contain it.
So, rather than the capitalist world's working class demanding
socialism, as Khrushchev dreamed, the working class of the Bolshevik experiment
demanded capitalism.
Unfortunately, what they got was capitalism with a double whammy of American ideology.
Unfortunately, what they got was capitalism with a double whammy of American ideology.
The Overnight Transition to
Capitalism
American economists saw the collapse of the Soviet system as
vindication, not just of the market over central planning – which was a valid
interpretation of history – but also of their own theory of capitalism. This
portrayed the main strength of the market as its ability to rapidly reach
equilibrium. Fantastically, they believed that simply by removing price
controls, Russia could transit from stagnant socialism to harmonious capitalism
virtually overnight. This statement from Murray Wolfson is typical of the glib
ideological stupidity proffered as advice by American economic advisers: "Central
planners seemingly should at once resign their posts and close their offices.
Their departure simply would signal the market to move immediately to
equilibrium." (Wolfson 1992, p. 37)
What market? The whole point of the transition from socialism was
to create a market economy, not to watch an already-existing one jump "immediately
to equilibrium." But that little detail seemed to escape
American economists, who recommended a rapid 'shock therapy' transformation of
the many once-socialist economies to market systems. Worries that this might
fail were dismissed with glib jokes.
Unfortunately, naïve mainstream economists weren't the only ones
pushing for a rapid transition. So too were America's political operators, who
saw it, not as an opportunity to transform Russia into a market economy, but as
a means to destroy a rival superpower. If shock therapy killed the patient,
great: where military force had been ineffective, economics could instead
cripple America's greatest rival.
Jeffrey Sachs, an architect of 'shock therapy' policies in Bolivia
and Poland who supported a rapid transition, saw the malicious nature of US
policy towards Russia, and found himself powerless to stop it, as he explained
in a Twitter exchange with me last year.
He still argues that a rapid transition could have worked, but says
that by "rapid" he meant over "5-10 years,
with rules and law." Instead, Russia's transition was first
planned to take 500 days, and was finally executed in less than 150 lawless
days.
The result was economic collapse, political chaos, and the morphing of the mafia (and many ex-Communists) into the Oligarchs, who took possession of many of the once state-owned enterprises, and much of Russia's publicly owned resources, during the so-called privatization process.
The result was economic collapse, political chaos, and the morphing of the mafia (and many ex-Communists) into the Oligarchs, who took possession of many of the once state-owned enterprises, and much of Russia's publicly owned resources, during the so-called privatization process.
For some Russians, the result of the transition was death. This was
brought home to me viscerally when I spoke at the Russian University of
Humanities in 2011. As we discussed our respective economics departments, my
Russian counterpart remarked that his department had more academics before the
transition. I asked what happened to the ones who had left. He gave me a
querulous look and responded: “They died.” He explained that
the deregulation of prices began on January 2, 1992, when many Russians were
still recovering from their New Year’s hangovers. They woke to find that prices
had quadrupled, while for most, their incomes remained the same.
The destructive impact of the far-too-rapid transition was an
increase in the mortality rate, which medical researchers concluded meant
that "an extra 2.5-3 million Russian
adults died in middle age in the period 1992-2001 than would have been expected
based on 1991 mortality. "
In strict economic terms, the transition was an abject failure –
that is, if you think it was intended to improve Russian living standards. GDP
virtually halved between 1990 and 1998, living standards plummeted, crime
proliferated, and Russian society almost collapsed. Even today, output is
barely above pre-transition levels.
The failure of the rapid transition policies forced on Russia by
the US is even more apparent when Russia’s transition performance is compared
with China’s, where the communists remained firmly in control, and where the
transition was deliberately undertaken at a measured pace. Russia’s per capita
GDP today is only slightly above its level at the end of the Soviet period.
China’s per capita GDP is ten times what it was in 1990.
The Strongman-led Recovery
However, viewed from the very bottom of this brutal process in
1998, Russia has made remarkable progress: from 1998 until now, GDP has more
than doubled, in both total and per capita terms.
For almost all of this time, Russia’s president or prime minister
has been Vladimir Putin.
Prior to his election in 2000, Putin rose to prominence in part
because of his successful repression of the Chechen revolt. This hardly
endeared Putin to the Chechens. But it gave him the aura of a strongman at the
time most Russians believed their country desperately needed one, to eliminate
the low-level mafia who tormented the public directly, to subdue the Oligarchs
who exploited them, and to stand up to the West when his predecessor Yeltsin
had effectively been a puppet.
Putin can’t be solely credited with starting the economic
turnaround, but his strongman approach to running Russia was welcomed, and is
still welcomed, by the majority of his countrymen.
Russia is far from perfect under Putin, and Putin is far from
perfect himself. But its economy and its national pride have been restored
under his rule, and the Russian public cannot be faulted for feeling
substantial antipathy towards the West, and the US in particular.
Given that Russia has legitimate grievances about how the West
treated it after it decided to join the capitalist camp, and the disastrous
outcomes of all previous Western attempts at regime change, I’d rather our
so-called leaders aimed for rapprochement with Russia, and yes, with Putin,
instead of heightened animosity.
No comments:
Post a Comment