November 6, 2018
Link: https://www.counterpunch.org/2018/11/06/why-iran-needs-a-war-economy/
Link: https://www.counterpunch.org/2018/11/06/why-iran-needs-a-war-economy/
Faced with the relentless U.S. economic war, Iran needs a war
economy. Indeed, the plan of a war economy should not be very difficult for
Iran to implement since it has a relatively successful experience of carrying
out such a plan: during the 8-year war with Saddam Hussein’s Iraq, Iran
embarked on an extensive state-guided economic management that effectively
provided for both its military and civilian needs. Because of the revolutionary
atmosphere of the time, and because of the corresponding spirit of generosity,
selflessness, social cohesion, and national unity the country was able to
effectively withstand both the military and economic wars launched against its
territory and its people. Despite the extremely costly war, both in terms of
blood and treasure, and despite the fact that Iran’s total output, or national
income, at the time was only a fraction of what it is today, its people did not
experience nearly as much economic hardship as they do today. Why? Mainly
because its national resources were at the time distributed relatively
equitably—unlike today where those resources are monopolized and plundered by a
clique of financial oligarchs and economic mafias.
To embark on a war-economy route, Iran needs, first and
foremost, to revive the real (value-producing) sector of its economy, that is,
manufacturing and agricultural activities. These real-value and employment
generating activities, which are the physical or material sources of the wealth of a nation, as the classical economist
Adam Smith put it, have become dormant under President Rouhani—largely by a
persistent and out-of-control barrage of imports, both legal and illegal.
To begin with, the government must embark on a large scale and
affordable construction of housing facilities. In addition to reducing the cost
of housing for low-income citizens, this would also revive many industries that
tend to feed as well as feed-off this industry. It is estimated that there are
nearly 200 industries that could be revived from an effective revival of the
housing industry. Indeed, despite the largely unfair criticism by the Rouhani
administration, the government-sponsored housing project that was carried out
by the previous (Ahmadinejad) administration not only succeeded in keeping the
cost of housing under control and, thereby, allowing 4.4 million low-income
families to become homeowners, it also significantly contributed to economic growth
and high employment rates of the time.
To revive its semi-paralyzed economy, Iran must also embark on a
policy of import-substitution,
combined with a policy of export-promotion.
Import-substitution simply means curtailing imports that can be substituted by
domestic products. Only those products that are essential for basic consumer
and manufacturing needs (but cannot be produced domestically) should be
imported. Such critically-needed foreign products must be imported directly by the government and distributed
through the chain networks of consumer cooperatives or municipal retail stores
at subsidized, affordable prices. Due to utter paralysis of market mechanism in
Iran, the government must simultaneously contain the skyrocketing inflation by
administrative means, that is, by strict laws against hoarding, price gouging,
and speculative transactions. To make the administrative price control
effective, the government must also restore the coupon system of pricing and
distribution it used during Iran-Iraq war.
An export promotion policy means supporting exporters of
domestic products, promoting their products abroad, standardizing and improving
the quality of such products, thereby broadening their sales markets beyond
national borders. In this connection, two important policy issues should be
kept in mind. First, only those products that are above and beyond domestic
consumer and manufacturing needs should be exported. Second, the export
earnings of foreign exchange must be returned to the national reserves of
foreign currencies.
Liberal-Neoliberal proponents of free trade would sneer at these
proposals as schemes of a planned or command economy. These proponents forget
or ignore the fact that proposals of these sort are no more than development
strategies of a guided capitalist economy; that almost all the presently
advanced capitalist economies, including the U.K. and the U.S., resorted to
such protectionist strategies in the early stages of their economic
development; and that even today the core capitalist country of the world, the
United States, is protecting its non-competitive industries such as steel,
aluminum, automobiles, and sugar against imports from China, Europe, Canada,
South Korea, and Japan. It is altogether ironic that while the most advanced
capitalist country in the world is resorting to protectionism and the erection
of tariff walls to support its non-competitive industries, President Rouhani
and his economic advisors are singing the song of free trade. These misguided
Iranian champions of free trade tend to be more catholic than the pope!
Crucial to a successful implementation of a war economy is
control of the country’s money and banking system, that is, of the financial
sector. A radically-different management of the nation’s money and banking
requires that the parasitic formation and growth of the shadow banks (or moasesat-e eatebari in Farsi), which are
essentially based on Ponzi or Pyramid schemes, be terminated. It further
requires that the commercial banks be prohibited by law from engaging in
non-bank, speculative activities. This is, indeed, what the United States did
in response to the Great Depression of the 1929-1933. That depression was
blamed largely on commercial banks’ parasitic investment and speculative loan
pushing, which created an unviable stock market bubble that eventually
collapsed on October 29, 1929. To prevent the recurrence of such a destructive
act of the banking system, the U.S. Congress instituted the landmark
Glass-Steagall Act that prohibited commercial banks from engaging in non-bank
activities, or speculative investments. Specifically, it prohibited them from
participating in the investment banking business.
More importantly, the power of money creation and, therefore,
control of money supply must be taken away from commercial banks and delegated
exclusively to the publicly-owned Central Bank of Iran (CBI). Following the
Anglo-Saxon model of fractional reserve banking, the power of money creation in
Iran rests not so much with the government, or Central Bank, as it does with
commercial banks. When commercial banks make loans or extend credit to their
clients, in effect, they create money, which is called debt money, or credit
money, or bank money, as opposed to sovereign or real money created by the
government. Although in essence bank
money is not real money, in practice it functions just as real money.
In theory, the ability of the banking system to create credit or
debt-money is determined or limited by (a) the amount of savings or deposits
they receive from households and businesses, and (b) the central bank
regulation of these deposits—a regulatory mechanism which is called fractional
reserve banking. In practice, however, the ability of the banking system to
create credit, or bank money, is not much constrained by the amount of deposits
they receive or by central bank regulation of money supply.
The ability of the commercial banking system to create money
explains why the all-important power of controlling or manipulating money
supply, of financing and, therefore, of influencing national economies in most
capitalist countries has increasingly come to rest with commercial banks—often
mediated by central banks and treasury departments that are frequently headed
by the proxies of the financial oligarchy.
What has made the ability of the commercial banking system to
create money—of course, debt or credit money—especially more dangerous in
recent years is that, as the financial sector has systematically freed itself
from traditional rules and regulations, most of the debt money they create is
increasingly geared towards speculation, not production. This explains the
exponential growth of parasitic finance in most capitalist countries. Parasitic
growth of the financial sector in Iran represents an extreme case of this
ominous development—a developments that has made the country’s economic
landscape akin to a nationwide casino (for more information on this point
please see here).
It follows that an effective cleansing of Iran’s economy of the
poisonous effects of parasitic finance requires (a) ending the commercial
banks’ ability to engage in speculative or non-banking activities, and (b)
ending their ability to create money. Aside from the destabilizing and
destructive economic effects, private banks’ ability to create money is also
problematic on legal and/or constitutional grounds. As a critically important
economic decision or policy of any nation, money creation is logically a
sovereign prerogative, that is, a national right; it belongs to the public, not
private, domain. The right of creating money ought to exclusively be granted to
the publicly-owned central bank as the monetary authority of the state. This
would replace sovereign money system for the currently corrupt bank- or
debt-money system based on fractional reserve banking.
In brief, Iran needs a government that could guide, manage,
monitor or control its international trade, its banking and financial markets,
its foreign exchange market, its money supply, and its natural endowments, or
gifts from nature, such as forests, water resource, oil, natural gas and other
underground resource. It also needs to put a leash on the corrupt privatization
of national resources and industries—a fraudulent practice that is used as a
pretext for the looting of public domain properties, or national wealth. It
further needs to embark on a state-guided extensive development or
industrialization plan, along with a relatively generous social safety net
program that would reduce inequality and economic hardship for the overwhelming
majority of its people.
The funding sources of such an ambitious developmental and
social safety-net projects are readily available—provided that there is
political will and managerial ability. One such a source of financing could be
provided by a reallocation of a larger portion of the oil revenue to such
projects. Since becoming president, Mr. Rouhani has reduced the share of the
reconstruction and development budget of the total national budget from over 20
percent less than 10 percent. By the same token he has drastically increased
the share of the largely ceremonial and wasteful current expenditures. A
re-allocation, or re-setting, of these two categories of the national budget to
pre-Rouhani days could free a significant amount of funding for social and
developmental expenditures.
A second, and more important, source of financing could come
from government funding through the publicly-owned Central Bank of Iran (CBI).
Instead of borrowing from abroad or from domestic private banks at interest,
CBI could print money (as needed) and directlyspend
it into the economy through social and developmental projects without going
into debt and paying interest. Champions of neoclassical-neoliberal school of
economic thought would scream at this suggestion, which is called deficit
spending for productive investment, that it would be inflationary. But it does
not have to be so. Whether it would be inflationary or not depends on the
management of the funds thus created. If they are used for productive
investment, they could lead to a rise of production, employment, economic
development and social progress—not inflation. Indeed, all the core capitalist
countries of the world, especially Germany, rebuilt their devastated economies
by the Great Depression and World War II largely by virtue of deficit
financing.
Strategies of a “resistance” or war economy along the lines
suggested here are rather well-known both in theory and practice. As noted
earlier, most of the advanced capitalist countries of today successfully
utilized such protectionist strategies of industrialization in the early stages
of their development. They switched from policies of economic protection and
strategic trade to policies of free trade only after they became
internationally competitive under protectionist strategies of trade and
development. Also as noted earlier, Iran too resorted to similar strategies of
economic protection and resistance during the 8-year war with Iraq, which
enabled it to successfully provide for both its civilian and military needs.
Even today Ayatollah Khamenei and a number of economists such as Ebrahim Razaghi,
Ahmad Tavakoli and their co-thinkers have been calling for the implementation
of a protectionist developmental strategy, which they call “resistance”
economics.
The main economic problem facing Iran today is, therefore, not a
lack of theoretical knowledge or practical experience; it is rather an absence
of political will and managerial ability of implementing such a strategy that
is crippling Iran’s economy. As I have shown in a number of previous essays, President Rouhani and his economic
advisors are too deeply wedded and/or committed to the doctrine of
liberal-neoliberal economics to carry out a war or resistance economic policy.
Implementation of such a policy, which is essential to the revival of Iran’s
paralyzed economy, requires a different administration: an inward-looking
administration that would rely on domestic resources, talents and capabilities;
not an outward-looking administration that pins its hopes for economic
development on Western capital, expertise and markets. Obviously, this implies
the need for an altogether new, revolutionary government.
No comments:
Post a Comment